dominance theorem - meaning and definition. What is dominance theorem
Diclib.com
ChatGPT AI Dictionary
Enter a word or phrase in any language 👆
Language:

Translation and analysis of words by ChatGPT artificial intelligence

On this page you can get a detailed analysis of a word or phrase, produced by the best artificial intelligence technology to date:

  • how the word is used
  • frequency of use
  • it is used more often in oral or written speech
  • word translation options
  • usage examples (several phrases with translation)
  • etymology

What (who) is dominance theorem - definition

PARTIAL ORDER BETWEEN RANDOM VARIABLES
Statistical dominance; Stochastic Dominance; First-order stochastic dominance; Statewise dominance; Second-order stochastic dominance

dominance         
WIKIMEDIA DISAMBIGUATION PAGE
Dominance (disambiguation); Dominance (biology); Dominant (biology)
¦ noun
1. power and influence over others.
2. Genetics the phenomenon whereby one allelic form of a gene is expressed to the exclusion of the other.
3. Ecology the predominance of one or more species in a plant or animal community.
Derivatives
dominancy noun
Strategic dominance         
  • left
  • frameless
  • frameless
  • frameless
  • frameless
  • frameless
  • frameless
  • 520x520px
QUALITY OF A STRATEGIC GAME PLAYER'S STRATEGY BEING BETTER THAN ANOTHER, FOR ALL OPPONENTS' STRATEGIES
Strictly dominated strategy; Strictly dominated strategies; Dominant strategy; Dominated strategy; Strict dominance; Iterated elimination of dominated strategies; Dominant strategy equilibrium; Iterated deletion; Domination (game theory); IEDS; Dominated strategies; Dominance (game theory); Dominant Strategy
In game theory, strategic dominance (commonly called simply dominance) occurs when one strategy is better than another strategy for one player, no matter how that player's opponents may play. Many simple games can be solved using dominance.
Divergence theorem         
  • n}}
  • A volume divided into two subvolumes. At right the two subvolumes are separated to show the flux out of the different surfaces.
  • The volume can be divided into any number of subvolumes and the flux out of ''V'' is equal to the sum of the flux out of each subvolume, because the flux through the <span style="color:green;">green</span> surfaces cancels out in the sum. In (b) the volumes are shown separated slightly, illustrating that each green partition is part of the boundary of two adjacent volumes
  • </math> approaches <math>\operatorname{div} \mathbf{F}</math>
  • The divergence theorem can be used to calculate a flux through a [[closed surface]] that fully encloses a volume, like any of the surfaces on the left. It can ''not'' directly be used to calculate the flux through surfaces with boundaries, like those on the right. (Surfaces are blue, boundaries are red.)
  • The vector field corresponding to the example shown. Vectors may point into or out of the sphere.
GENERALIZATION OF THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM IN VECTOR CALCULUS
Gauss' theorem; Gauss's theorem; Gauss theorem; Ostrogradsky-Gauss theorem; Ostrogradsky's theorem; Gauss's Theorem; Divergence Theorem; Gauss' divergence theorem; Ostrogradsky theorem; Gauss-Ostrogradsky theorem; Gauss Ostrogradsky theorem; Gauss–Ostrogradsky theorem
In vector calculus, the divergence theorem, also known as Gauss's theorem or Ostrogradsky's theorem, reprinted in is a theorem which relates the flux of a vector field through a closed surface to the divergence of the field in the volume enclosed.

Wikipedia

Stochastic dominance

Stochastic dominance is a partial order between random variables. It is a form of stochastic ordering. The concept arises in decision theory and decision analysis in situations where one gamble (a probability distribution over possible outcomes, also known as prospects) can be ranked as superior to another gamble for a broad class of decision-makers. It is based on shared preferences regarding sets of possible outcomes and their associated probabilities. Only limited knowledge of preferences is required for determining dominance. Risk aversion is a factor only in second order stochastic dominance.

Stochastic dominance does not give a total order, but rather only a partial order: for some pairs of gambles, neither one stochastically dominates the other, since different members of the broad class of decision-makers will differ regarding which gamble is preferable without them generally being considered to be equally attractive.

Throughout the article, ρ , ν {\displaystyle \rho ,\nu } stand for probability distributions on R {\displaystyle \mathbb {R} } , while A , B , X , Y , Z {\displaystyle A,B,X,Y,Z} stand for particular random variables on R {\displaystyle \mathbb {R} } . The notation X ρ {\displaystyle X\sim \rho } means that X {\displaystyle X} has distribution ρ {\displaystyle \rho } .

There are a sequence of stochastic dominance orderings, from first 1 {\displaystyle \succeq _{1}} , to second 2 {\displaystyle \succeq _{2}} , to higher orders n {\displaystyle \succeq _{n}} . The sequence is increasingly more inclusive. That is, if ρ n ν {\displaystyle \rho \succeq _{n}\nu } , then ρ k ν {\displaystyle \rho \succeq _{k}\nu } for all k n {\displaystyle k\geq n} . Further, there exists ρ , ν {\displaystyle \rho ,\nu } such that ρ n + 1 ν {\displaystyle \rho \succeq _{n+1}\nu } but not ρ n ν {\displaystyle \rho \succeq _{n}\nu } .

Stochastic dominance could trace back to (Blackwell, 1953), but it was not developed until 1969–1970.